1. Background (a) In 2013, the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System (Board) issued a final regulatory capital
rule (Regulation Q) in coordination with the Office of the Comptroller
of the Currency (OCC) and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) that strengthened risk-based and leverage capital requirements
applicable to insured depository institutions and depository institution
holding companies (banking organizations).
1 Among those changes
was the introduction of a countercyclical capital buffer (CCyB) for
large, internationally active banking organizations.
2 (b) The CCyB
is a supplemental, macroprudential policy tool that the Board can
increase during periods of rising vulnerabilities in the financial
system and reduce when vulnerabilities recede. It is designed to increase
the resilience of large banking organizations when there is an elevated
risk of above-normal losses. Increasing the resilience of large banking
organizations will, in turn, improve the resilience of the broader
financial system. Above-normal losses often follow periods of rapid
asset price appreciation or credit growth that are not well supported
by underlying economic fundamentals. The circumstances in which the
Board would most likely begin to increase the CCyB above zero percent
to augment minimum capital requirements and other capital buffers
would be
when systemic vulnerabilities are meaningfully above normal.
By requiring large banking organizations to hold additional capital
during those periods of excess and removing the requirement to hold
additional capital when the vulnerabilities have diminished, the CCyB
also is expected to moderate fluctuations in the supply of credit
over time. Moderating the supply of credit may mitigate or prevent
the conditions that contribute to above-normal losses, such as elevated
asset prices and excessive leverage, and prevent or mitigate reductions
in lending to creditworthy borrowers that can amplify an economic
downturn. In this way, implementation of the CCyB also responds to
the Dodd-Frank Act's requirement that the Board seek to make its capital
requirements countercyclical.
3 (c) Regulation
Q established the initial CCyB amount with respect to private sector
credit exposures located in the United States (U.S.-based credit exposures)
at zero percent and provided that the maximum potential amount of
the CCyB for credit exposures in the United States was 2.5 percent
of risk-weighted assets.
4 The Board expects to make decisions
about the appropriate level of the CCyB for U.S.-based credit exposures
jointly with the OCC and FDIC, and expects that the CCyB amount for
U.S.-based credit exposures will be the same for covered depository
institution holding companies and insured depository institutions.
The CCyB is designed to take into account the macrofinancial environment
in which banking organizations function and the degree to which that
environment impacts the resilience of advanced approaches institutions.
Therefore, the appropriate level of the CCyB for U.S.-based credit
exposures is not closely linked to the characteristics of an individual
institution. Rather, the impact of the CCyB on any single institution
will depend on the particular composition of the private-sector credit
exposures of the institution across national jurisdictions.
2. Overview and Scope of the Policy Statement This Policy Statement describes the framework
that the Board will follow in setting the amount of the CCyB for U.S.-based
credit exposures. The framework consists of a set of principles for
translating assessments of financial system vulnerabilities that are
regularly undertaken by the Board into the appropriatelevel of the
CCyB. Those assessments are informed by a broad array of quantitative
indicators of financial and economic performance and a set of empirical
models. In addition, the framework includes an assessment of whether
the CCyB is the most appropriate policy instrument (among available
policy instruments) to address the highlighted financial system vulnerabilities.
3. The Objectives of the CCyB (a) The objectives of the CCyB are to
strengthen banking organizations' resilience against the build-up
of systemic vulnerabilities and reduce fluctuations in the supply
of credit. The CCyB supplements the minimum capital requirements and
the capital conservation buffer, which themselves are designed to
provide substantial resilience to unexpected losses created by normal
fluctuations in economic and financial conditions. The capital surcharge
on global systemically important banking organizations adds an additional
layer of defense for the largest and most systemically important institutions,
whose financial distress can have outsized effects on the rest of
the financial system and the real economy.
5 However, periods of financial excesses,
for example as reflected in episodes of rapid asset price appreciation
or credit growth not well supported by underlying economic fundamentals,
are often followed by above-normal losses that leave banking organizations
and other financial institutions undercapitalized. Therefore, the
Board would most likely begin to increase the CCyB above zero in those
circumstances when systemic vulnerabilities become meaningfully above
normal and progressively raise the CCyB level if vulnerabilities become
more severe.
(b) The CCyB is expected
to help provide additional resilience for advanced approaches institutions,
and by extension the broader financial system, against elevated vulnerabilities
primarily in two ways. First, advanced approaches institutions will
likely hold more capital to avoid limitations on capital distributions
and discretionary bonus payments resulting from implementation of
the CCyB. Strengthening their capital positions when financial conditions
are accommodative would increase the capacity of advanced approaches
institutions to absorb outsized losses during a future significant
economic downturn or period of financial instability, thus making
them more resilient.
(c) The second and related
goal of the CCyB is to promote a more sustainable supply of credit
over the economic cycle. During a credit cycle downturn, better-capitalized
institutions have been shown to be more likely than weaker institutions
to have continued access to funding. Better-capitalized institutions
also are less likely to take actions that lead to broader financial-sector
distress and its associated macroeconomic costs, such as large-scale
sales of assets at prices below their fundamental value and sharp
contractions in credit supply.
6 Therefore, it is likely that as a result of the CCyB having
been put into place during the preceding period of rapid credit creation,
advanced approaches institutions would be better positioned to continue
their important intermediary functions during a subsequent economic
contraction. A timely and credible reduction in the CCyB requirement
during a period of high credit losses could reinforce those beneficial
effects of a higher base level of capital, because it would permit
advanced approaches institutions either to realize loan losses promptly
and remove them from their balance sheets or to expand their balance
sheets, for example by continuing to lend to creditworthy borrowers.
(d) During a period of cyclically increasing vulnerabilities,
advanced approaches institutions might react to an increase in the
CCyB by raising lending standards, otherwise reducing their risk exposure,
augmenting their capital, or some combination of those actions. They
may choose to raise capital by taking actions that would increase
net income, reducing capital distributions such as share repurchases
or dividends, or issuing new equity. In this regard, an increase in
the CCyB would not prevent advanced approaches institutions from maintaining
their important role as credit intermediaries, but would reduce the
likelihood that banking organizations with insufficient capital would
foster unsustainable credit growth or engage in imprudent risk taking.
The specific combination of adjustments and the relative size of each
adjustment will depend in part on the initial capital positions of
advanced approaches institutions, the cost of debt and equity financing,
and the earnings opportunities presented by the economic situation
at the time.
7 4. The Framework for Setting the
U.S. CCyB (a) The Board regularly monitors
and assesses threats to financial stability by synthesizing information
from a comprehensive set of financial-sector and macroeconomic indicators,
supervisory information, surveys, and other interactions with market
participants.
8 In forming its view about the appropriate size of the U.S.
CCyB, the Board will consider a number of financial system vulnerabilities,
including but not limited to, asset valuation pressures
and
risk appetite, leverage in the nonfinancial sector, leverage in the
financial sector, and maturity and liquidity transformation in the
financial sector. The decision will reflect the implications of the
assessment of overall financial system vulnerabilities as well as
any concerns related to one or more classes of vulnerabilities. The
specific combination of vulnerabilities is important because an adverse
shock to one class of vulnerabilities could be more likely than another
to exacerbate existing pressures in other parts of the economy or
financial system.
(b) The Board intends to monitor
a wide range of financial and macroeconomic quantitative indicators
including, but not limited to, measures of relative credit and liquidity
expansion or contraction, a variety of asset prices, funding spreads,
credit condition surveys, indices based on credit default swap spreads,
option implied volatilities, and measures of systemic risk.
9 In addition, empirical models
that translate a manageable set of quantitative indicators of financial
and economic performance into potential settings for the CCyB, when
used as part of a comprehensive judgmental assessment of all available
information, can be a useful input to the Board's deliberations. Such
models may include, but are not limited to, those that rely on small
sets of indicators—such as the nonfinancial credit-to-GDP ratio, its
growth rate, and combinations of the credit-to-GDP ratio with trends
in the prices of residential and commercial real estate—which some
academic research has shown to be useful in identifying periods of
financial excess followed by a period of crisis on a cross-country
basis.
10 Such models may also include those that
consider larger sets of indicators, which have the advantage of representing
conditions in all key sectors of the economy, especially those specific
to risk-taking, performance, and the financial condition of large
banks.
11 (c) However, no single indictor or fixed
set of indicators can adequately capture all the vulnerabilities in
the U.S. economy and financial system. Moreover, adjustments in the
CCyB that were tightly linked to a specific model or set of models
could be imprecise due to the relatively short period that some indicators
are available, the limited number of past crises against which the
models can be calibrated, and limited experience with the CCyB as
a macroprudential tool. As a result, the types of indicators and models
considered in assessments of the appropriate level of the CCyB are
likely to change over time based on advances in research and the experience
of the Board with this new macroprudential tool.
(d) The Board will determine the appropriate level of the CCyB for
U.S.-based credit exposures based on its analysis of the above factors.
Generally, a zero percent U.S. CCyB amount would reflect an assessment
that U.S. economic and financial conditions are broadly consistent
with a financial system in which levels of system-wide vulnerabilities
are within or near their normal range of values. The Board could increase
the CCyB as vulnerabilities build. A 2.5 percent CCyB amount for U.S.-based
credit exposures, which is the maximum level under the Board's rule,
would reflect an assessment that the U.S. financial sector is experiencing
a period of significantly elevated or rapidly increasing system-wide
vulnerabilities. Importantly, as amacro-prudential policy tool, the
CCyB will be activated and deactivated based on broad developments
and trends in the U.S. financial system, rather than the activities
of any individual banking organization.
(e) Similarly,
the Board would remove or reduce the CCyB when the conditions that
led to its activation abate or lessen. Additionally, the Board would
remove or reduce the CCyB when release of CCyB capital would promote
financial stability. Indeed, for the CCyB to be most effective, the
CCyB should be deactivated or reduced in a timely manner. Deactivating
the CCyB in a timely manner could, for example, promote the prompt
realization of loan losses by advanced approaches institutions and
the removal of such loans from their balance sheets and would reduce
the likelihood that advanced approaches institutions would significantly
pare their risk-weighted assets in order to maintain their capital
ratios during a downturn.
(f) The pace and magnitude
of changes in the CCyB will depend importantly on the underlying conditions
in the financial sector and the economy as well as the desired effects
of the proposed change in the CCyB. If vulnerabilities are rising
gradually, then incremental increases in the level of the CCyB may
be appropriate. Incremental increases would allow banks to augment
their capital primarily through retained earnings and allow policymakers
additional time to assess the effects of the policy change before
making subsequent adjustments. However, if vulnerabilities in the
financial system are building rapidly, then larger or more frequent
adjustments may be necessary to increase loss-absorbing capacity sooner
and potentially to mitigate the rise in vulnerabilities.
(g) The Board will also consider whether the CCyB is the
most appropriate of its available policy instruments to address the
financial system vulnerabilities highlighted by the framework's judgmental
assessments and empirical models. The CCyB primarily is intended to
address cyclical vulnerabilities, rather than structural vulnerabilities
that do not vary significantly over time. Structural vulnerabilities
are better addressed through targeted reforms or permanent increases
in financial system resilience. Two central factors for the Board
to consider are whether advanced approaches institutions are exposed—either
directly or indirectly—to the vulnerabilities identified in the comprehensive
judgmental assessment or by the quantitative indicators that suggest
activation of the CCyB and whether advanced approaches institutions
are contributing—either directly or indirectly—to these highlighted
vulnerabilities.
(h) In setting the CCyB for advanced
approaches institutions that it supervises, the Board plans to consult
with the OCC and FDIC on their analyses of financial system vulnerabilities
and on the extent to which advanced approaches banking organizations
are either exposed to or contributing to these vulnerabilities.
5. Communication of the U.S.
CCyB with the Public (a) The Board
expects to consider at least once per year the applicable level of
the U.S. CCyB. The Board will review financial conditions regularly
throughout the year and may adjust the CCyB more frequently as a result
of those monitoring activities.
(b) Further, the
Board will continue to communicate with the public in other formats
regarding its assessment of U.S. financial stability, including financial
system vulnerabilities. In the event that the Board considered that
a change in the CCyB were appropriate, it would, in proposing the
change, include a discussion of the reasons for the proposed action
as determined by the particular circumstances. In addition, the Board's
biannual
Monetary Policy Report to Congress, usually published
in February and July, will continue to contain a section that reports
on developments pertaining to the stability of the U.S. financial
system.
12 That portion of the report will be an important
vehicle for updating the public on how the Board's current assessment
of financial system vulnerabilities bears on the setting of the CCyB.
6. Monitoring the Effects of
the U.S. CCyB (a) The effects
of the U.S. CCyB ultimately will depend on the level at which it is
set, the size and nature of any adjustments in the level, and the
timeliness with which it is increased or decreased. The extent to
which the CCyB may affect vulnerabilities in the broader financial
system depends upon a complex set of interactions between required
capital levels at the largest banking organizations and the economy
and financial markets. In addition to the direct effects, the secondary
economic effects could be amplified if financial markets extract a
signal from the announcement of a change in the CCyB about subsequent
actions that might be taken by the Board. Moreover, financial market
participants might react by updating their expectations about future
asset prices in specific markets or broader economic activity based
on the concerns expressed by the regulators in communications announcing
a policy change.
(b) The Board will monitor and
analyze adjustments by banking organizations and other financial institutions
to the CCyB: whether a change in the CCyB leads to observed changes
in risk-based capital ratios at advanced approaches institutions,
as well as whether those adjustments are achieved passively through
retained earnings, or actively through changes in capital distributions
or in risk-weighted assets. Other factors to be monitored include
the extent to which loan growth and interest rate spreads on loans
made by affected banking organizations change relative to loan growth
and loan spreads at banking organizations that are not subject to
the buffer. Another consideration in setting the CCyB and other macroprudential
tools is the extent to which the adjustments by advanced approaches
institutions to higher capital buffers lead to migration of credit
market activity outside of those banking organizations, especially
to the nonbank financial sector. Depending on the amount of migration,
which institutions are affected by it, and the remaining exposures
of advanced approaches institutions, those adjustments could cause
the Board to favor either a higher or a lower value of the CCyB.
(c) The Board will also monitor information regarding
the levels of and changes in the CCyB in other countries. The Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision is expected to maintain this information
for member countries in a publically available form on its Web site.
13 Using that data
in conjunction with supervisory and publicly available datasets, the
Board will be able to draw not only upon the experience of the United
States but also that of other countries to refine estimates of the
effects of changes in the CCyB.